Divorce and Female Labor Force Participation:

Evidence from Times-Series Data, Causality Tests, and Cointegration

 

 

by

 

Dale Bremmer

Professor of Economics

Department of Humanities and Social Sciences

Rose-Hulman Institute of Technology

5500 Wabash Avenue

Terre Haute, IN 47803

Phone: (812)877-8456

Fax:(812)877-8909

Email: dale.bremmer@rose-hulman.edu

 

and

 

Randy Kesselring

Professor of Economics

Department of Economics and Decision Sciences

Arkansas State University

P.O. Box 239

State University, AR 72467-0239

Phone: (870)972-3416

Fax:(870)910-8187

Email: randyk@astate.edu

 

 

 

 

 

 

To be presented at

The “Issues in Labor Economics” Session of

The 44th Annual Meetings of the Western Social Science Association

Albuquerque, New Mexico

April 11, 2002

 


Divorce and Female Labor Force Participation:

Evidence from Times-Series Data, Causality Tests, and Cointegration

 

 

I.    Introduction

        Divorce, female labor force participation, and median real annual income for females are important indicators of the economic status of women in the United States.  Over the last fifty years, each of these factors has experienced significant increases.  The number of divorces per 1,000 married women age 15 years or older increased from 11.2 in 1948 to 19.8 in 1995 reaching a high of 22.8 in 1979.  Female labor force participation increased from 32.7 percent in 1948 to 58.9 percent in 1995, the highest participation rate during the period.  The median real income for women increased 121 percent during this period, from $6,149 (2000 = 100) in 1948 to $13,620 in 1995.

        The sizable increase in the number of divorces (see Figure 1) has led to much research and conjecture regarding the factors that influence the decision to dissolve a marriage.  This increase has been attributed to, among other factors, the sexual revolution of the Sixties, the emergence of no-fault divorce procedures, the diminished stigma associated with being divorced, and the increased acceptance of divorced individuals as suitable spouses.  However, early researchers placed a great deal of emphasis on the idea that increasing female labor force participation (see Figure 2) placed various “pressures” on the household and, ultimately, resulted in larger numbers of divorces.  Closely tied to this argument is the indisputable relationship between income and labor force participation.  As female incomes rise (see Figure 3), divorce, the argument goes, becomes more likely.

      Using time-series techniques, this paper investigates the relationship between divorce, female labor force participation, and median female income.  Though it is shown that these variables exhibit unit roots, their first differences are found to be stationary, and evidence is produced that they are cointegrated.  In other words, the cointegration techniques of Johansen and Juselius show the existence of a long-run relationship between these variables.

      A VAR of the first differenced data is estimated using an error-correction technique.  Impulse functions from this model reveal that an increase in divorce leads to a rise in female labor force participation; but, positive innovations to female labor force participation imply a decline in the divorce rate.  Impulse function analysis also shows that a positive innovation to median female income leads to increased divorce and increased labor force participation on the part of females.

      The rest of the paper consists of five additional sections.  Section II provides a relatively thorough review of the literature regarding marital dissolution.  Section III gives a complete discussion of the data and its sources along with the unit roots tests for the various time series.  The fourth and fifth sections present the cointegration and the vector error correction model results.  Finally, in Section VI, conclusions and recommendations for further research are provided.

II.  Literature review

      There have been many studies of divorce in the United States and they have used a wide assortment of techniques, variables and data to produce results that often seem contradictory and, sometimes even, counterintuitive.  Variables used to predict divorce have included marriage tenure; working status of the female; the husband’s earnings, age, and educational level; the wife’s earnings, age, and educational level; the number and age of children; and the occurrence of a previous divorce.  Macroeconomic variables such as the unemployment rate, the inflation rate and the rate of growth in real GDP have also been used to explain the observed increase in divorce. 

      Lombardo [1999], and Greene and Quester [1982] argue that wives facing a higher risk of divorce will hedge against that risk with higher levels of labor force participation, and that they will also respond by working longer hours.  The basic argument made in these papers is that investment in nonmarket activities, such as child rearing, becomes relatively less attractive (it yields a lower expected return), and investment in human capital becomes relatively more attractive (it yields a higher expected return) as the probability of divorce increases.  Studies by Johnson and Skinner [1986], and Shapiro and Shaw [1983] provide additional evidence for the above argument by finding that women increase their labor force participation prior to dissolution of a marriage.  The above papers make a clear causality argument that an increase in the likelihood of divorce increases a females willingness to enter the labor force. 

      Spitze and South in two separate studies [1985, 1986] argue a different line of causality.  Their conclusion is that an increase in female labor force participation leads to an increase in familial conflict and, consequently, an increase in divorce.  Substantiating evidence for this view is provided by Mincer [1985] who, in a survey of twelve industrialized nations, found that rising divorce rates clearly lag rising female labor force participation rates.

      Previous studies of the impact of income on divorce have provided mixed results.  Becker, Landes, and Michael [1977] find that a rise in expected female earnings increases the probability of divorce, while a rise in expected male earnings reduces the probability of divorce. D’amico [1983] recognizes two distinctly different possible effects of income on divorce.  One hypothesis is that as the female’s wage relative to the male’s rises, conflict based on competition for status within the marriage will occur and will increase the likelihood of divorce.  The second, opposing hypothesis, is the notion that the pursuit of higher socioeconomic status is a familial one and that a wife earning a relatively higher wage than that of the husband may contribute to the overall status goal and solidify the marriage.  D’amico’s results tend to confirm the latter hypothesis.  Finally, Hoffman and Duncan [1995] find no support for the hypothesis that increased real wages for females lead to increased divorce rates.

      However, Spitze and South raise another question that is closely related to the income issue.  In a 1985 study, they produce evidence that the number of hours a wife works has a greater impact on the probability of divorce than do various measures of the wife’s income.

      Using time-series analysis, South [1985] finds little evidence that the divorce rate rises during periods of recession and falls during periods of expansion.  He does find a positive, albeit small, effect of unemployment on the divorce rate.  His model indicates that changes in the age structure and the labor force participation rate of women have significantly stronger impacts on the divorce rate than other macroeconomic variables.

      Finally, using a simple vector autoregressive (VAR) approach, Bremmer and Kesselring [1999] show that the female labor force participation rate does not Granger cause divorce rates.  However, they do provide statistical evidence that divorce rates Granger cause female participation in the labor force.  They also show that past participation in the labor market influences women salaries.

III. The data and unit root tests

      Annual time-series data for the divorce rate, the female labor force participation rate, and the level of median real female income are readily available.  Data on the divorce rate was obtained from the National Center of Health Statistics of the Centers for Disease Control.[1]  The level of real median female income was acquired from the U.S. Census Bureau.[2]  The labor force participation rate for women sixteen years and older was obtained from the Bureau of Labor Statistics.[3] 

      One of the main contributions to the study of macroeconomic time-series is the importance of verifying whether a time-series is stationary.  Time series that are nonstationary have unit roots and can be characterized as random walks.  In regard to regression analysis, if both the dependent variables and the independent variables are nonstationary, spurious results may occur.  In this case, traditional statistical inference using standard t-tests and F-tests would tend to reject the hypothesis that there is no relationship between the dependent and explanatory variables when, in fact, no underlying relationship between the variables exist.[4]  To ensure that inferences from time-series regressions are valid, one has to statistically test whether the data series exhibit unit roots. To accomplish this, the augmented Dickey-Fuller [1979] test and the Phillips-Perron [1988] test are used.

      Let Z be a time series variable. If Z follows an autoregressive scheme, then Zt = ρZt-1 + ut, where , and ut is a white noise, random error term.  If Z follows a random walk, then Z has a unit walk, implying ρ = 1.  The augmented Dickey Fuller test detects unit roots by estimating the regression

           (1)

where t is a time trend, ΔZt = Zt – Zt-1, and εt is the error term.  In equation (1),  δ, β0, β1, and ωi, i = 1, ... , m,  are regression parameters to be estimated.   The null hypothesis of a nonstationary random walk implies δ equals 0.  The number of lagged dependent variables included as explanatory variables depends on how long the lag length needs to be to ensure that εt is not serially correlated.

      The results of the augmented Dickey-Fuller tests are reported in Table 1.  In the case of all three of the variables - - the divorce rate, the female labor force participation rate, and the median female real income - - the null hypothesis of a zero root is not rejected.  However, the first differences of this data do appear to be stationary.  In the case of the first differences of the divorce rates, the null hypothesis of a unit root is rejected at the 10 percent level.  The null hypotheses of unit roots in the first differences of the female labor force participation rate and median real female income is rejected at the 1 percent level.  Given the statistical evidence that the first differences of these data series are stationary, these variables are said to be integrated of order one, or I(1).

      Further evidence that the first differences of these variables are stationary is shown in Table 2, which shows the Phillips-Perron unit root tests.  This test differs from the augmented Dickey-Fuller test by correcting for autocorrelation parametrically, thus preserving the larger sample sizes by not having to add lagged dependent variables to eliminate autocorrelated error terms. Using levels data, this tests fails to reject the null hypothesis of unit roots for all three of the variables. However, once the data is first differenced, the Phillips-Perron tests indicate that all three series are stationary.  Using first-differenced data, the null hypothesis of unit roots is rejected at the one percent level for first-differences in the female labor force participation and real median female income.  The null hypothesis of nonstationary is rejected at the five percent level in the case of first differences of the divorce rate.  Therefore, in a finding that is consistent

with the augmented Dickey-Fuller results, the Phillips-Perron test results reported in Table 2 indicate that each of these three data series is I(1).

IV. Cointegration tests

      If the three time series--divorce rate, female labor force participation rate, and median real income--all have unit roots, a vector autoregression (VAR) of these variables may lead to misleading, spurious results.  However, there may exist a linear combination of these variables that is stationary.  This stationary, linear relationship of the nonstationary time-series variables is called a cointegrating equation, and it is often interpreted as the true, long-run relationship between the variables.

      The increasing prevalence of VAR’s in time series estimations derives from the problems usually confronted by economists wishing to avoid specification errors common to most time-series methods.  For most econometric models, the choice of specification can be a very thorny issue.  The typical specification search is strictly one of trial and error.  Frequently, different functional forms and combinations of possible explanatory variables are selected and tested.  The reason for this is that economic theory may not conclusively indicate the impact of a given variable, nor may it conclusively indicate which variables should be included in--or, for that matter, excluded from--the model’s specification.  Furthermore, theory may do little to reveal the true functional form of the model.

      Therefore, to minimize the possibility of specification errors, to exploit the simultaneity of the variables chosen for the model, and to circumvent the possibility of making incorrect distinctions between exogenous and endogenous variables, a VAR model was chosen to explain the relationship between the divorce rate, the female labor force participation rate, and the level of median real female income.  In a VAR framework, each endogenous variable is a function of past values of all endogenous variables.  In addition, successive lagged endogenous variables are added to the specification until the error term is no longer autocorrelated.

      Let the divorce rate in year t equal Dt, the female participation rate in year t be Lt, and the median real female income in year t be Yt.  The VAR is a system of three equations specified as follows:

       (2)

      (3)

      (4)

      Each of the above equations was estimated using ordinary least squares (OLS).  It could certainly be argued that the error terms in equations (2) - (4) are correlated and, therefore, a technique such as seemingly unrelated regressions (SUR) should be used for their estimation rather than a single-equation estimator such as OLS. However, because each of the equations has exactly the same explanatory variables, the OLS estimates and the SUR estimates are identical.

      The choice of the lag length, m, can be guided by using the Akaike information criterion (AIC), the Schwartz criterion, or likelihood ratio tests.  Another deciding factor is that the lag length must be sufficiently long so that the error terms in equations (2)-(4) are all white noise.  In examining lag lengths of m = 2, m = 3, or m = 4, likelihood ratio tests indicate that a lag length of  m = 3 is optimal.[5]  Testing the null hypothesis of m = 2 with an alternative hypothesis of m =3, the likelihood ratio test statistic is 16.76 with a p-value of 0.052.[6] This implies that the null hypothesis of m = 2 can be rejected at the ten-percent level.  However, when the null hypothesis of m = 3 is compared to an alternative hypothesis of m = 4, the resulting chi-squared test statistic is 8.76 with a p-value of 0.46.[7]  This implies that the null hypothesis of m = 3 cannot be rejected even at the ten-percent level.

      Given the decision that the lag length of the VAR is equal to three, the next step is to determine whether the three are cointegrated.  The trace tests suggested by Johansen and Juselius [1990] and Johansen [1991] are used.  These tests are based on assumptions regarding whether the cointegrating vector includes an intercept or a trend, or whether the VAR exhibits a deterministic trend.  Johansen proposes five alternatives consisting of different combinations of assumptions.  Table 3 reports the five different sets of assumptions proposed by Johanson along with the Akaike information criterion (AIC) scores used to test which set of assumptions should be applied to the current problem.  The alternative with the smallest AIC (6.90) is model 5.  It assumes that the cointegrating vector includes both an intercept and a trend, and that the underlying VAR exhibits a quadratic trend.

      Table 4 reports the results of applying Johansen’s trace test to a model based on the assumptions set forth in alternative 5 (described above) along with a lag length of 3.  With a test statistic of 36.69, the null hypothesis of no cointegrating vector is rejected at the 5 percent level.  However, the null hypothesis that the number of cointegrating vectors is at most one has a test statistic of 12.94, implying that the null hypothesis cannot be rejected at the five-percent level.  Finally, the null hypothesis of at most two cointegrating vectors is rejected at the five percent level.  The statistical conclusion is that there is one cointegrating vector.

      Table 5 reports the coefficients of the normalized cointegrating equation and the corresponding regression statistics for the associated VAR.  The estimated coefficients for the female labor force participation rate and the level of median real income are statistically significant at the ten-percent level or better.  The cointegrating relation is plotted in Figure 7, which shows that the divorce rate was greater than its long-run level during most of the Sixties and Seventies.

V.  Vector error correction and impulse functions

      Because the divorce rate, the female labor participation rate, and the level of median real female income are cointegrated, estimation of a vector error correction (VEC) model is the appropriate next step.  The vector error correction technique is essentially a restricted VAR that includes the cointegrating equation in the model’s specification.  The model is estimated with the data in first difference form, not in levels, and while it allows short-run dynamics, the VEC model includes a restriction that each variable must converge to its long-run, cointegrating relationship.

      The parameter estimates of the VEC model are reported in Table 6.  While one does not usually emphasize the statistical significance of the individual slope coefficients in a VAR or VEC format, the model’s performance is mixed.  The coefficient for the cointegrating equation’s error correction term, which is included in each equation as an explanatory variable, is only statistically significant in the female labor force participation equation.  The only significant variable in the divorce equation is the time trend and only the one period lag of the first difference in real income is statistically significant in the income equation.  An F-test of the null hypothesis that all slope coefficients are zero is rejected for the divorce and labor force participation equations but not for the income equation.

      R-squared calculations for these equations vary widely with values ranging from a high of 0.606 for the divorce equation to a low of 0.197 for the income equation.  It is important to remember that the dependent variables of these equations are all expressed in first differences.  Once the predicted changes in the dependent variables are converted to levels data, the model’s ability to explain variations in the data becomes more apparent.  Figure 4 plots the actual and predicted divorce rates in levels data.  The R-squared value for this procedure is 0.9902.  The actual and predicted levels of the female labor force participation rate are shown in Figure 5, and the close fit is indicative of the level form R-squared of 0.9981.  The model also predicts median real female income (in level form) quite well.  The actual and predicted values for this variable are plotted in Figure 6, and the recalculated R-squared is 0.9824.

      The interpretation of the magnitude, sign and significance of an individual slope coefficient in a VEC model is problematical.  After all, the reason for including the lag structure in a VEC model is to eliminate serial correlation, improve forecasting, and avoid misspecification problems when theory is inconclusive about the underlying functional form or the specific set of explanatory variables that should be included.  Therefore, it should come as no surprise that a technique other than slope interpretation is used for prediction purposes.  [See Stock and Watson, 2001] Consequently, to study the effect of any given change on an explanatory variable, a common practice is to analyze impulse response functions.  The impulse response function reveals what happens to a given dependent variable if there is a change or innovation in the error term of one of the other equations in the system.  In the results that follow, the innovation in each of the impulse response functions was a one standard deviation increase in the error term of one of the other equations. 

      The response of the divorce rate to an increase in the female labor force participation rate is shown in Figure 8.  An increase in female labor force participation leads to a decrease in the divorce rate.  A very possible explanation for this result is that the wife’s contribution to family income reduces economic pressures on the family and, consequently, decreases the probability of divorce.  This is an interesting result when compared to previous studies such as the one by Hannan, Tuma and Groenveld [1978].  It has long been argued that working outside the family contributes to income and income usually contributes to family stability (In the literature, this is referred to as the income effect of female employment).  However, a persistent argument has been made that rising female labor force participation increases the female’s level of independence and, along with it, the probability of divorce (In the literature, this is referred to as the independence effect).   The evidence produced by this study clearly indicates that an increase in female labor force participation does not increase the likelihood of divorce.

        These results are mitigated somewhat by the impulse response function in Figure 11 which indicates that increases in female income do lead to rising divorce rates.  This finding is in opposition to those produced by Greenstein [1990] who argues that increases in income contribute to marital stability.  It does appear that separating the income effect from the independence effect has been problematical.   The evidence produced by this study points to the importance of both the independence effect and the income effect. Employment may increase martial stability, but higher returns from employment may result in greater numbers of dissolved marriages.

      The impulse response function pictured in Figure 9 reveals that rising divorce rates correspond to rising female labor force participation.  There are two probable reasons for this relationship.  First, women who have experienced divorce surely enter the labor force in order to offset the loss of income and wealth inevitably associated with marital dissolution.  However, another key interpretation of this result is that a rising divorce rate sends a signal to all married females that the probability of remaining married for a lifetime is waning.  The appropriate and predictable response is for females to substitute away from nonmarket activities (housework and child rearing) to market activities (work).  Greater female investment in human capital is the predictable outcome, and is confirmed by the results provide in Figure 9. 

      Finally, Figure 10 shows the effect of an innovation in median female income on labor force participation.  Increases in median female income lead to increases in female labor force participation.  This is not a surprising result.  The incentive to work rises and females respond to the incentive.[8]

VI. Conclusions and thoughts for future work

      Results in this paper indicate that the divorce rate, the female labor force participation rate, and the median level of real female income have unit roots, and that time-series regression with level data may produce spurious results.  These variables are integrated of order one, and there exists a single, cointegrating relationship between them.  Furthermore, the single cointegrating equation implies that these variables have a single, underlying long-run relationship. 

      The most interesting results derive from application of impulse response functions to the set of equations.  Previous studies on divorce have argued that female labor force participation could have dual effects on marital dissolution.  The “income effect” argues that female labor force participation increases income and reinforces familial relationships, thereby leading to a reduction in the likelihood of divorce.  A counter argument in the literature focuses on the “independence effect.”  This effect hypothesizes that female labor force participation increases income, financial independence and, consequently, the probability of divorce.   Time series results from this paper argue for the existence of both effects.   Increases in female labor force participation appear to reduce the likelihood of divorce.  However, the evidence clearly indicates that increases in female income lead to increases in the likelihood of divorce.  Without doubt, income is a much better indicator of financial independence than simple labor force participation.

     
Bibliography

 

Becker, Gary S., Elisabeth M. Landes, and Robert T. Michael, “An Economic Analysis of Martial Instability, “ Journal of Political Economy, 1977, vol. 85, no. 6, 1141-1187.

 

Bremmer, Dale and Randy Kesslering, “The Relationship between Female Labor Force Participation and Divorce: A Test Using Aggregate Data,” unpublished mimeo, 1999.

 

Breusch, T.S., “Testing for Autocorrelation in Dynamic Linear Models,” Australian Economic Papers, 1978, vol. 17, 334-355.

 

D’amico, Ronald, “Status Maintenance or Status Competition? Wife’s Relative Wages as a Determinant of Labor Supply and Martial Instability,” Social Forces, June 1983, vol. 61, no. 4, 1186-1205.

 

Dickey, D. A. and W. A. Fuller, “Distribution of the Estimators for Autoregressive Time Series with a Unit Root,” Journal of the American Statistical Association, 1979, vol. 74, 427-431.

 

Godfrey, L.G., “Testing against General Autoregressive and Moving Average Error Models When the Regressors Include Lagged Dependent Variables,” Econometrica, 1978, vol. 46, 1293-1302.

 

Greene, William H. and Aline Q. Quester, “Divorce Risk and Wives’ Labor Supply Behavior,” Social Science Quarterly, March 1982, vol. 63, no. 1, 16-27.

 

Greenstein, Theodore N., “Marital Disruption and the Employment of Married Women,” Journal of Marriage and the Family, Aug. 1990, vol. 52, no. 3, 657-677.

 

Hannan, Michael T., Nancy Brandon Tuma and Lyle P. Groenveld, Income and Independence Effects on Marital Dissolution: Results from the Seattle and Denver Income-Maintenance Experiments,” American Journal of Sociology, 1978, vol. 84, no. 3, 611-633.

 

Hoffman, Saul and Greg Duncan, “The Effect of Incomes, Wages, and AFDC Benefits on Martial Disruption,” The Journal of Human Resources, vol. 30, no. 1, 19-41.

 

Johansen, Soren, and Katarina Juselius, “Maximum Likelihood Estimation and Inferences on Cointegration – with Applications to the Demand for Money,” Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 1990, vol. 52, 169-210.

 

Johansen, Soren, “Estimation and Hypothesis Testing of Cointegrated Vectors in Gaussian Vector Autoregressive Models,” Econometrica, vol. 59, 1551-1580.

 

Johnson, William R. and Jonathan Skinner, “Labor Supply and Martial Separation,” American Economic Review, June 1986, vol. 76, no. 1, 455-469.

 

Lombardo, Karen V., “Women’s Rising Market Opportunities and Increased Labor Force Participation,” Economic Inquiry, April 1999, vol. 37, no. 2, 195-212.

 

Mincer, Jacob, “Intercountry Comparisons of Labor Force Trends and Related Developments: An Overview,” Journal of Labor Economics, 1985, vol. 3, no. 1, pt. 2, S1-32.

 

Nelson, C. R. and C. I. Plosser, “Trends and Random Walks in Macroeconomic Time Series: Some Evidence and Implications,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 1982, vol. 10, 139-162.

 

Shapiro, David and Lois Shaw, “Growth in Supply Force Attachment of Married Women: Accounting for Changes in the 1970's,” Southern Economic Journal, September 1985, vol. 6, no. 3, 307-329.

 

South, Scott, “Economic Conditions and the Divorce Rate: A Time-Series Analysis of Postwar United States,” Journal of Marriage and the Family, February 1985, vol. 47, no. 1, 31-41.

 

South, Scott and Glenna Spitze, “Determinants of Divorce over the Martial Life Course,” American Sociological Review, August 1986, vol. 51, 583-590.

 

Spitze, Glenna, and Scott South, “Women’s Employment, Time Expenditure, and Divorce,” Journal of Family Issues, September 1985, vol. 6, no. 3, 307-329.

 

Stock, James H. and Mark W. Watson, “Vector Autoregressions,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, Fall 2001, vol. 15, no. 4, 101-115.


Table 1

Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) Unit Root Test

 

 

 

 

Regression Assumptions

Statistic

Critical Values

Variable (Annual Data)

Data Type

Data

Lags

Constant

Trend

Divorce Rate

Levels

′51-′95

2

Yes

No

1.68

2.60

3.58

Divorce Rate

1st Differences

′51-′95

1

No

No

1.77***

1.62

2.61

Female Labor Force Participation

Levels

′50-′95

1

Yes

Yes

1.95

3.18

4.17

Female Labor Force Participation

1st Differences

′51-′95

1

Yes

No

4.17*

2.60

3.58

Median Real Female Income

Levels

′50-′95

1

Yes

Yes

2.16

3.18

4.17

Median Real Female Income

1st Differences

′51-′95

1

Yes

No

3.92*

2.60

3.68

                    *(***) indicates the null hypothesis of a unit root is rejected at 1%(10%) level.

 

 

 

Table 2

Phillips-Perron Unit Root Tests

 

 

 

 

Statistic

Critical Values

Variable (Annual Data)

Data Type

Data

Divorce Rate

Levels

′49-′95

0.66

2.93

3.57

Divorce Rate

1st Differences

′50-′95

3.12**

2.93

3.58

Female Labor Force Participation

Levels

′49-′95

1.80

3.51

4.16

Female Labor Force Participation

1st Differences

′50-′95

4.37*

2.93

3.58

Median Real Female Income

Levels

′49-′95

2.42

3.51

4.16

Median Real Female Income

1st Differences

′50-′95

4.54*

2.93

3.58

                                            *(**) indicates the null hypothesis of a unit root is rejected at 1%(5%) level.

 

 

 


Table 3

Summary of Johansen Cointegration Tests: Akaike Information Criteria

Model Assumptions

Model 1

Model 2

Model 3

Model 4

Model 5

Deterministic Data Trend:

No

No

Linear

Linear

Quadratic

Assumptions Pertaining to

Cointegrating Equation(s):

Intercept?

No

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Trend?

No

No

No

Yes

Yes

Rank or Number of Cointegrating Equation(s)

Model 1

Model 2

Model 3

Model 4

Model 5

0

7.29

7.29

7.19

7.19

7.17

1

7.10

7.14

7.16

6.96

6.90

2

7.24

7.27

7.24

6.99

7.00

3

7.51

7.46

7.46

7.15

7.15

 

Table 4

Johansen Cointegration Test - - Trace Tests: Model 5

Eigenvalue

Likelihood

Ratio

5 Percent

Critical Value

1 Percent

Critical Value

Hypothesized Number of

 Cointegrating Equation(s)

0.42

36.69

34.55

40.49

None *

0.16

12.94

18.17

23.46

At most 1

0.11

5.14

3.74

6.40

At most 2 *

            * denotes rejection of the hypothesis at 5% significance level

 

Table 5

Vector Error Correction, Cointegrating Equation, and VAR Summary Statistics

Cointegrating Equation

Dt-1

1.0000

Lt-1

-357.0525*

 

(-6.4298)

Yt-1

0.0013***

 

(2.0130)

Time Trend

1.6305

Intercept

93.9237

Regression Statistics for VAR

Determinant Residual Covariance

0.0339

Log Likelihood

-112.8565

Akaike Information Criteria

6.9026

Schwartz Criteria

8.4840

 t-statistics in parentheses.  *, **, *** implies the estimated coefficient is statistically different from zero at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level, respectively.


Table 6

Vector Error Correction - - VAR Estimates with First Differences - - Sample: 1952 - 1995

 

 

Dependent Variables

 

ΔDt

ΔLt

ΔYt

Intercept

0.15873

0.00373

52.24672

 

(0.86682)

(2.77166)

(0.54177)

Time Trend

-0.01394**

0.00006

1.90524

 

(-2.35161)

(0.12930)

(0.61023)

Cointegrating Equation

0.05438

0.00154*

-1.73559

 

(1.13283)

(4.37362)

(-0.06865)

Divorce Rate ΔDt-1

0.12942

-0.00401*

-52.97690

 

(0.67870)

(-2.86360)

(-0.52753)

Divorce Rate ΔDt-2

0.24050

-0.00162

-36.00333

 

(1.14026)

(-1.04694)

(-0.32413)

Divorce Rate ΔDt-3

-0.04470

-0.00307***

57.74148

 

(-0.21224)

(-1.98314)

(0.52059)

Participation Rate ΔLt-1

28.12394

0.47665

6835.48100

 

(1.41965)

(3.27428)

(0.65517)

Participation Rate ΔLt-2

-14.34733

0.02986

2100.30500

 

(-0.62931)

(0.17826)

(0.17576)

Participation Rate ΔLt-3

13.98764

0.09411

-4988.19400

 

(0.64635)

(0.59180)

(-0.43767)

Real Income ΔYt-1

0.00050

0.0000002

0.34146***

 

(1.37504)

(0.07171)

(1.80105)

Real Income ΔYt-2

0.00013

-0.0000008

-0.04123

 

(0.33071)

(-0.28903)

(-0.20066)

Real Income ΔYt-3

0.00056

0.000002

0.05900

 

(1.55628)

(0.84103)

(0.31278)

 

 

 

 

R2

0.606

0.570

0.197

F

4.427*

3.855*

0.714

t-statistics in parentheses.  *, **, *** implies the estimated coefficient is statistically different from zero at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level, respectively.


Table 7

Data Appendix

 

Year

 Dt

Lt

Yt

 

Year

 Dt

Lt

Yt

1948

11.2

32.70%

$6,149

 

1972

17.0

43.90%

$9,328

1949

10.6

33.10%

5,922

 

1973

18.2

44.70%

9,444

1950

10.3

33.90%

5,808

 

1974

19.3

45.70%

9,471

1951

9.9

34.60%

5,898

 

1975

20.3

46.30%

9,607

1952

10.1

34.70%

6,360

 

1976

21.1

47.30%

9,598

1953

9.9

34.40%

6,409

 

1977

21.1

48.40%

9,943

1954

9.5

34.60%

6,335

 

1978

21.9

50.00%

9,840

1955

9.3

35.70%

6,130

 

1979

22.8

50.90%

9,623

1956

9.4

36.90%

6,208

 

1980

22.6

51.50%

9,790

1957

9.2

36.90%

6,268

 

1981

22.6

52.10%

9,928

1958

8.9

37.10%

5,970

 

1982

21.7

52.60%

10,118

1959

9.3

37.10%

6,171

 

1983

21.3

52.90%

10,427

1960

9.2

37.70%

6,250

 

1984

21.5

53.60%

10,898

1961

9.6

38.10%

6,278

 

1985

21.7

54.50%

11,076

1962

9.4

37.90%

6,524

 

1986

21.2

55.30%

11,476

1963

9.6

38.30%

6,581

 

1987

20.8

56.00%

12,097

1964

10.0

38.70%

6,859

 

1988

20.7

56.60%

12,501

1965

10.6

39.30%

7,093

 

1989

20.4

57.40%

12,978

1966

10.9

40.30%

7,420

 

1990

20.9

57.50%

12,930

1967

11.2

41.10%

7,916

 

1991

20.9

57.40%

12,975

1968

12.5

41.60%

8,533

 

1992

21.2

57.80%

12,928

1969

13.4

42.70%

8,634

 

1993

20.5

57.90%

12,993

1970

14.9

43.30%

8,643

 

1994

20.5

58.80%

13,197

1971

15.8

43.40%

8,908

 

1995

19.8

58.90%

13,620

Dt = Divorce rate per 1000 married women 15 years and over.  Source: http://www.cdc.gov/ nchs/fastats/divorce.htm.  Lt = female labor force participation rate for women 16 years and older.  Source: http://www.bls.gov/webapps/legacy/cpsatab1.htm.  Yt = U.S. female median real income (in 2000 dollars).  Source: http://www.census.gov/hhes/income/histinc/p05.html.


Figure 1

Divorces Per 1000 Married Women Age 15 Years and Older: Annual Data, 1948 – 1995

 

 

 

Figure 2

Female Labor Force Participation Rate Age 16 Years and Older: Annual Data, 1948 – 1995


Figure 3

Real Female Median Income (in 2000$): Annual Data, 1948 – 1995

 


 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Figure 4

Results from Error-Corrected VAR: Predicted and Actual Divorce Rates

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 


Figure 5

Results from Error-Corrected VAR: Predicted and Actual Female Labor Force Participation

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 


Figure 6

Results from Error-Corrected VAR: Predicted and Actual Female Real Median Income

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 



Figure 7

Cointegrating Vector - - Deviation from the Long-Run Level

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 


Figure 8

Response of Divorce Rate to Innovation in Labor Force Participation

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 



Figure 9

Response of Female Labor Force Participation to Innovation in Divorce Rate

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 


Figure 10

Response of Female Labor Force Participation to Innovation in Median Female Real Income

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 



Figure 11

Response of Divorce Rate to Innovation in Median Female Real Income

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 



[1]See the divorce data at http://www.cdc.gov/nchs/fastats/divorce.htm.

[2]See http://www.census.gov/hhes/income/histinc/p05.html.

[3]This data can be found at http://www.bls.gov/webapps/legacy/cpsatab1.htm.

[4] Nelson and Plosser (1982) is the classic paper that analyzes this problem with macroeconomic time series.

[5] The test for the optimal lag length used the same sample of annual data between 1952 and 1995.

[6] This likelihood ratio test is distributed chi-squared with nine degrees of freedom.

[7] This chi-squared variable also has nine degrees of freedom.

[8] Often the results of analyzing the impulse response functions depends on the order the innovations are introduced in the VEC.  The qualitative outcome of the impulse response functions was the same regardless of the ordering.